What Works Scotland Directors James Mitchell and Ken Gibb examine prevention and what stands in the way of making progress in a shift to prevention.
There is a consensus that the Christie Commission’s emphasis on
shifting to prevention is the right direction of travel if outcomes are to be
improved for people and communities and reduce future demands on public
services. There is also a consensus that this is not happening at the pace
desired. What stands in the way of progress?
How can it be overcome?
We have found that the well-established public-policy framework of Ideas, Institutions, and Interests,
is a useful way to frame this discussion. In developing work in this area, we
have also interviewed practitioners across a range of services. Taking each of
the three ‘I’s in turn we can identify key impediments.
Ideas
The academic literature distinguishes between different forms of
prevention: primary, secondary and tertiary or upstream and downstream [1]. Practitioners often do not see these
distinctions as important – preferring early focus on a problem or issue and
how it can be addressed at this stage. It is not so much the idea of prevention that
is contested as where prevention sits alongside public service activities.
Prevention is only one amongst a number of public service ideas and
not always the priority in service delivery.
Prevention competes with policy enforcement, prioritizing between short
run policy choices, responsive policy, and crisis management for the attention
of policy-makers. Each of these is
important and no serious policy-maker, at local or national levels would place
more emphasis on prevention if it meant abandoning any of the others. In many cases, these distinctions break
down. Almost all policies can be
presented as having a responsive element.
In policing, for example, the enforcement of a law may ensure that
future infringements are prevented.
Triage nursing, as with any triage approach in public policy, is defined
as early assessment in order to identify priorities. Done well, it involves preventing the
deterioration of an existing condition.
Crisis management is similar.
The emphasis on prevention needs to be set alongside these other
ideas and demands.
Institutions
It is long well established that institutions have path dependent
properties ie it is very difficult for any institution to change course once
working practices have been established.
Institutions adopt practices that become deeply embedded. A significant change of emphasis may sound
simple but exhortation is not enough.
Familiar practices become engrained norms.
Not only are practices engrained but we currently set short- to
medium-term goals and targets that place little, if any, emphasis on long-term
prevention. As the long-term is little
more than the combination of short-terms, then we can hardly be surprised that
our long-term goals are not met if short-term goals are different from
long-term goals.
A fundamental shift to prevention will not be easily achieved even
when a consensus exists to move in that direction.
Adopting or giving greater priority to prevention when public
services are already under pressure raises questions as to how this shift
should occur and who will take the lead.
Prevention may be the better approach in the long term but Keynes’
famous comment is apposite, ‘in the long run, we are all dead’. In the short and medium term, public services
must address immediate challenges. Public
service is judged by the immediate.
Punishments, plaudits and promotion are all awarded in response to
recent past and immediate activities.
Prevention will often involve a shift across a range of public services
and it will not always be easy to identify culpability for the failure to make
the shift or credit when it is achieved.
Our public services are judged in terms that make it very difficult to
prioritise prevention.
To put it crudely, there is little credit for prevention.
Interests
This brings us to interests.
It is in the collective interest to shift to prevention but not
necessarily, at least in the short term, in the interest of any single
institution. In a world of tight public
finances, a shift in resources (whether money, time or effort) involves a cut
elsewhere. Everyone looks to everyone
else to make the shift and progress is not realised. We face the familiar prisoners’ dilemma.
And the game-theoretic ideas can be extended usefully. A
non-co-operative structure of inter-institutional relationships may be frowned
upon, but it would be naïve to think that this never can occur. Nor would it be
sensible to ignore the possibility of non-altruistic behaviour by senior
bureaucrats in such circumstances. How do we move towards a co-operative game,
one in which opportunities for prevention and collaboration are encouraged and
rewarded?
Implications
So far, the message is bleak. We want a
shift to prevention but are unable to effect it, at least at pace. But acknowledging what appears to be a bleak
situation is the first stage towards addressing the challenge.
Three responses are proposed:
- Ideas and mindsets in training and workplace.
- Incentivise a shift to prevention and disincentivise other practices.
- Force the pace by removing institutional impediments.
Ideas and Mindsets
There remains a remarkable lack of emphasis on prevention in
recruitment and socialisation. Consider
the job descriptions and training in a range of public services. How often is prevention emphasized or even
mentioned? Leadership plays an important
part in this. If the message from the
top is not on prevention then the behaviour through any service is unlikely to
give it priority. There is a need to
consider the extent to which the very idea of prevention is given anything like
the place it ought to be given.
All public services would be well served by conducting an audit on
prevention in its internal messaging. This should include an internally managed
but participative mapping of the types of spending and activity undertaken by
the organization to encourage creative thinking and identifying prevention
organically.
Institutions
Our institutions operate in silos in which each looks to others to
lead on prevention. This is most evident
in the financial silos that operate within public services. It is frequently asserted that a shift in
resource towards prevention by one institution will only benefit others. This relates strongly to the above
observation on short-termism and non-co-operation.
Current institutional arrangements rest on the hope that different
institutions will find common cause in pursuing common long-term
objectives. This might happen but it
runs contrary to immediate rational behaviour.
There needs to be an examination of short- to medium-term goals and
targets. If the emphasis here fails to
permit space for prevention then we should not be surprised if there is no
shift to prevention. From the outset of collaborations, inter-agency activities
and joint projects, the mindset and priority of prevention needs to be embedded
by leaders and in the work of their staff. It should be a fundamental aspect of
any inter-organisational working. This, rather than focusing on outcomes over a
defined period, is where the decisive shift to prevention may actually occur –
in the embedding of processes that will, over time, achieve a range of
prevention benefits.
There needs to be a closer examination of the goals and targets set
to ensure an emphasis on long-term at the expense of short- to medium-term
efforts.
Interests
Aligning interests and objectives may seem obvious but currently
there is little effort to do this. The suggestion is that we need to think
again about the set of rewards and incentives for pursuing prevention that are
used to encourage public service workers, organisations and collaborations
between agencies. Is there a public sector equivalent to something akin to a
private sector consortium savings pool where contractors can share in savings
made by cutting costs against targets?
NOTE
1. See: P.Hardiker, K. Exton,
and M. Barker, Literature Reviews: Crime Prevention and Prevention in Health
Care, University of Leicester, Report for the Department of Health 1986.
No comments:
Post a Comment
Note: only a member of this blog may post a comment.